Apple v. Samsung and the road to Patent Sanity
Apple’s attempt to grab all of Samsung’s profits highlights the need for major reform
When Apple CEO Tim Cook unveiled the iPhone 6 and 6 Plus in
September, amid the “oohs” and “ahs,” some of us were thinking, “Wow,
these stretched iPhones look a lot like Samsung’s Galaxy devices.”
So it’s ironic that the two companies just resumed a years-long war over Samsung’s supposed copying of Apple’s
products in a D.C. federal court. Apple claims that in the smartphone’s
early days, Samsung’s device shapes and graphical icons too closely
resembled the iPhone’s. After Apple tried, but failed, to ban
importation of all Samsung devices, a jury awarded Apple an astounding
$929 million. Another case awarded Apple $120 million — though Apple had
been seeking more than $2 billion. This summer the firms settled some
40 disputes around the world, which leaves the two big U.S. verdicts,
both of which are under appeal.
The numbers are so large
because a quirk of the 1887 law governing “design patents” seemingly
allows for the disgorgement of the “total profit” derived from the
infringing products. Yet there is controversy over the meaning of the
law in a modern technological economy. And like the debate over suspect
software patents, many question the very validity of some types of
design patents, which cover not technical functionality but appearance,
or “look and feel.”
Apple v. Samsung is
important because of its place in what I call the “patent reformation.”
Over the last several decades, we issued far too many patents of dubious quality
— often for software code, or business practices, or appearance, as in
the Apple-Samsung cases. The flood of patents fueled a litigation
explosion, and the link between intellectual property and real
innovation frayed. In a new report,
for example, the Congressional Budget Office shows that the large
increase in patent applications and awards over the last three decades
has not boosted productivity growth.
Most
technology and policy experts over the last few years came to agree on
the need for major reform. Last session, Congress narrowly failed to
enact a major intellectual-property overhaul. But in June, the Supreme
Court revised software patent law, in the landmark CLS Bank v. Alice Corp. case. Since then, courts have been invalidating software patents at a faster rate than ever. “Among the invalidated patents,” notes The Wall Street Journal,
“was one involving an online dieting tool, another for a computer bingo
game, and yet another for using a computer to convert reward points
from one company's loyalty program to another’s.” In addition to a
tightening of judicial reins, a number of big technology companies,
including Google, have voluntarily settled major disputes, leaving
Apple-Samsung as the unresolved stand-off in what Steve Jobs called the
“thermonuclear” smartphone wars.
The question is whether the remedy in these cases — the award to the plaintiff of the total profits earned by the defendant’s product — makes any sense in the modern world.
A
smartphone is a complex integration of thousands of hardware and
software technologies, manufacturing processes, aesthetic designs and
concepts. These components may each be patented, or licensed, or not at
all, by any number of firms. A smartphone, by one estimate, may contain
up to 250,000 patents. Does a minor design patent comprising a tiny
fraction of a product’s overall makeup drive the purchase decision? If
company A’s product contains one infringing component among many
thousands, even if it has no knowledge or intent to infringe, and even
if the patent should never have been issued, does it make sense that
company B gets all company A’s profits?
Advocates of the total-profit penalty say all this is
irrelevant. Read the plain text of the 1887 law, they say. The phrase —
“shall be liable to the owner to the extent of his total profit” — may
appear to support their view. But why couldn’t “total profit” mean the
total profits of the firm? Fortunately, a more natural reading is at
hand. Given the realities of highly integrated modern technologies, the
phrase “to the extent” can easily be read to limit the award in
proportion to the severity of the infringement. This is more in keeping
with the law of trademarks and copyrights, which (although imperfect
themselves) more closely resemble design “patents” and often provide for
more common sense remedies.
Absolutists reply that the
total profit penalty is the only effective deterrent against
counterfeiting. They say proportional penalties would be like royalties,
a simple cost of doing business, and thus would not discourage
counterfeiting. This, however, presumes the quality control of the
issued design patents. When “designs” are everywhere, no one can hope to
completely avoid infringement, and thus no one is safe from the total
loss of one’s profits.
Intellectual property is a
crucial foundation of innovation and economic growth. But too many
frivolous patents and lawsuits render it a tool not of invention but of
destructive gamesmanship. If the appeals court reins in total-profit
penalties, the patent reformation will achieve another important
advance.
Bret Swanson is president
of Entropy Economics LLC, a strategic insight firm specializing in
technology, innovation and the global economy, and president of Entropy
Capital, a firm that invests in both public companies and private
technology ventures. He is also a scholar at the U.S. Chamber of
Commerce Foundation and a visiting fellow at the American Enterprise
Institute’s technology research program.
No comments:
Post a Comment